Contents

Description of CHPV and GV

Introduction
Analogy
Weightings
Voting
Counting
Outcomes
Party-List
Summary

Evaluations of CHPV and GV

Ranked Ballot

Introduction (RB)
General Criteria
Majority Criteria
Clones & Teaming
Teaming Thresholds
Summary (RB)

Party-List

Introduction (PL)
Diagrams & Maps
CHPV Maps
Optimality
Party Cloning
Proportionality
Summary (PL)

Comparisons of CHPV with other voting systems

Single-Winner

Introduction (SW)
Plurality (FPTP)
Borda Count
Geometric Voting
Positional Voting
Condorcet Methods
AV (IRV)
Plur. Rule Methods
Summary (SW)

Multiple-Winner

Introduction (MW)
STV
Party-List
PL ~ Hare
PL ~ Droop
~ Maps Opt PC Pro
PL ~ D'Hondt
~ Maps Opt PC Pro
PL ~ Sainte-Laguë
~ Maps Opt PC Pro
Mixed Member Sys
Summary (MW)

Conclusions

Ranked Ballot CHPV
Party-List CHPV

General

Table of Contents

Map Construction

Table of Contents

Mathematical Proofs

Table of Contents
Notation & Formats

Valid XHTML 1.0 Strict

Valid CSS

Home About Description Evaluations(RB) Evaluations(PL) Comparisons(SW) Comparisons(MW) Conclusions General Maps Proofs
Home About Description Evaluations(RB) Evaluations(PL) Comparisons(SW) Comparisons(MW) Conclusions General Maps Proofs
Home > Proofs > Geometric Voting > CG5
Last Revision: 02 Oct 2020

Mathematical Proofs: Geometric Voting

Proof CG5: Minimum Winning Rank for a Consensus Candidate

Scenario: There are V voters in a single-winner election with N candidates. One candidate receives the nth preference from every voter and is hence referred to as the consensus candidate C. The tally for C is then simply V times the weighting of the nth preference (wn); as stated below. All the remaining (N-1) candidates receive an equal share of each of the other (N-1) preferences. Therefore, each such candidate has the same number of first, second and other preferences (except the nth) as the other non-consensus candidates. These N-1 candidates have equal tallies and are critically tied when ranked above the consensus candidate. Let one of these tied candidates (with the evenly distributed preferences) be D. The tally for D is derived below.

Candidate Tallies

For the consensus candidate C to gain victory in the election, the tally for C must be greater than the tally for D. The criterion for this victory is derived below.

Weighting Criteria

If the non-consensus candidates have any other distribution of the preferences awarded to them (that is, an unequal one), then they will not all be tied. Some will then have higher tallies and others lower ones. It will now be even more difficult for the consensus candidate to beat the top-ranked one.


Return to main text > Comparisons: Geometric Voting 6

Refer to > Mathematical Proofs: Table of Contents